Rabu, 20 Februari 2008

Agrarian Reform and Rural Development: Historical Overview and Current Issues

ISS/UNDP Land, Poverty and Public Action Policy Paper No. 1

Agrarian Reform and Rural Development:
Historical Overview and Current Issues

Saturnino M. Borras Jr.
Cristóbal Kay
A. Haroon Akram Lodhi

ISS/UNDP ‘Land Policies, Poverty Reduction and Public Action’ Research Project
Rural Development, Environment and Populations Studies Group
Institute of Social Studies (ISS)
Kortenaerkade 12, 2518AX The Hague, The Netherlands
Tel: +31 70 4260460; www.iss.nl/land ; Email: land@iss.nl

Introduction
Land reform is back on the policy agenda of international development institutions as
well as of many nation states. Globally, poverty still has primarily a rural face with
two-thirds of the world’s poor constituted by the rural poor. Its persistence has defied
policy makers for decades despite sustained efforts by national governments,
international institutions and civil society. Effective control over productive
resources, especially land, by the rural poor is crucial to their capacity to construct a
rural livelihood and overcome poverty. This is because in many agrarian settings a
significant portion of the income of the rural poor still comes from farming, despite
far-reaching livelihood diversification processes that occurred in different places over
time.1 Hence, lack of access to land is strongly related to poverty and inequality.2 It is
therefore not altogether surprising that the World Bank’s 2006 World Development
Report that focuses on the question of equity has underscored the importance of land
access (World Bank, 2005, chapter 8). However, policy discussions around the
Millennium Development Goals are yet to systematically and significantly include the
issue of wealth and power redistribution in the rural areas, i.e. agrarian reform,
especially in a situation where majority of the world’s poor are rural poor
(CPRC,2005).
But unlike in past theorizing and practice of land reform, where the central
state took a commanding role, in contemporary thinking about land policies a decisive
role is assigned to ‘free’ market forces in land re-allocation and use.3 More than a
decade into its experimentation and implementation, the new type of land reform
should be examined more systematically, both in theory and practice, as to whether it
has delivered what it has promised, and if not, why not. Yet, it is important that a
parallel critical evaluation of ongoing conventional state-directed land reforms
wherever these have been implemented must be carried out as well. The end goal is to
produce empirically grounded conceptual reflection on land policies and their
relevance to rural poverty eradication within the changed and changing global,
national and local context.
This land policy paper series gathers evidence on the impact of the different
land policies, and the varying strategies and approaches to implement them, on
reducing poverty and social exclusion in the rural areas, with an end view of
identifying possible sets of workable alternative policy options in contemporary
1 A recent comprehensive crossnational comparative study is Bryceson, Kay, and Mooij (2000). The
explanation by Ellis (2000) about livelihood diversification due to necessity or by choice offers
relevant analytic insights. Lahiff and Scoones (2000) offer equally important insights.
2 Important studies on the relationship between lack of access to land and poverty include Griffin
(1976, 1974) and El-Ghonemy (1990); most recent re-arguments within broadly similar framework but
amidst changing context include Herring (2003). De Janvry, Gordillo, Platteau, and Sadoulet (2001) is
a recent collection of (generally economic) studies that include both mainstream scholars and others
who do not necessarily or fully subscribe to the current mainstream economic doctrines.
3 Deininger and Binswanger (1999) and World Bank (2003) are the landmark publications that are key
to understanding the main features of the contemporary mainstream land policies. The World
Development Report 2006 (on equity and development) has addressed the issue of land access, but has
not put forward any new insights and has simply repeated the arguments and claims in other World
Bank documents and by other mainstream economists, dismissing the growing body of literature that is
critical of these arguments and claims (World Bank, 2005, chapter 8).
1
developing countries and transitional economies. This study maps out and critically
analyzes the different types of land policies that have been carried out in a number of
national settings. It has been guided by a broad conceptualization of redistributive
land reform that includes land titling, restitution of indigenous lands, indigenous land
claims, land settlement, tenancy and rental arrangements, farm consolidation and
parcelization, along with the complementary measures necessary to facilitate the
success of redistributive reform. Finally, this introductory essay puts the discussion in
this land policy paper series within the broader historical perspective and identifies
common themes that have been subject of the country case studies.
The ten countries examined in this study are Armenia, Bolivia, Brazil, Egypt,
Ethiopia, Namibia, the Philippines, Uzbekistan, Vietnam, and Zimbabwe. These ten
countries, cutting across regions, represent broad types of historical contexts within
which different land policies have been carried out more recently. The historical
context is important to take into consideration partly because it provides us a good
idea about the character of the pre-existing agrarian structure and its relationship with
existing poverty – the main objects of the redistributive agenda in any land reform.
The first type involves those countries that have not seen significant land
reform in the past but since the 1990s land reform has emerged as important
component of the national development policy and political agendas and has seen
greater degrees of implementation. In this research project, this is represented by
Brazil and the Philippines. Both countries have seen state-driven attempts to
redistribute some lands in the 1950s-1970s, but with less than significant outcomes in
terms of the quantity of lands redistributed. Both countries have had witnessed strong
militant peasant movements in the 1950s-1960s, been under military dictatorship, and
have witnessed regime national transition almost at the same time, in the mid-1980s,
coinciding with the resurgence of militant rural social movements demanding land
reform (Fox, 1990; Lara and Morales, 1990; Franco, 2001). Carmen Deere and
Leonilde Servolo de Medeiros as well as Saturnino Borras Jr., Danilo Carranza and
Ricardo Reyes analyze land policies in Brazil and the Philippines, respectively, and
explain why and how have the land reform been resurrected in these countries in the
mid-1980s onward, and with what outcomes. As shown in these studies, both
countries have also witnessed the introduction of broadly pro-market approaches to
land reform beginning in the later part of the 1990s onward – side by side the
existence of a state-driven land reform program – and Deere and Medeiros as well as
Borras et al examine such approaches and their initial outcomes, particularly looking
into their impact on poverty and inequality. Finally, both countries have active
contemporary agrarian reform movements, and these are analyzed within an
‘interactive framework’ in the study of state-society relations (Fox, 1993, 2004).
The second type pertains to those national settings that have had significant
land reforms in the past within broadly capitalist oriented development frameworks,
but that there are important ongoing changes in land policies that have profound
implications to the peasantry. In this land policy paper series, this type is represented
by Bolivia and Egypt as both countries have undergone important land reforms in the
1950s-1960s, although these major land reforms had not resulted in significant
degrees of poverty reduction in both countries, and both countries are currently
confronted by important changes in land policy regimes. Cristóbal Kay and Miguel
Urioste, as well as Ray Bush, examine the past land policies and their impact on
2
poverty in Bolivia and Egypt, respectively. They also critically analyze the key
features of contemporary adjustments being made in land policies in these countries,
and their impact on poverty and social exclusion.
The third type involves those countries that have undergone socialist
construction in the past, but are now currently promoting varying forms and degrees
of market-oriented land policies. In this research undertaking, this type is represented
by Armenia, Ethiopia, Uzbekistan, and Vietnam. These countries, with different
historical backgrounds, had carried out socialist-oriented land reforms in the past,
biased in favor of a combination of farm collectives and state farms. Since the early
1990s, all of these countries started to carry out, in varying extents and pace, broadly
pro-market land policies, giving importance to individualized property rights over
land, with varying outcomes and implications. Max Spoor (Armenia), Gebru Mersha
and Mwangi wa Githinji (Ethiopia), Azizur Rahman Khan (Uzbekistan), and Haroon
Akram Lodhi (Vietnam) examine the historical evolution of the land policies in these
four countries, the recent market-oriented changes in land policies, and their
subsequent impact on poverty and inequality.
The fourth type pertains to those countries that did not have a long history of
land policies, and that the ongoing land policies that are very much framed within the
post-colonial context. This type is represented, in this land policy paper series, by
Zimbabwe and Namibia. In both countries, land policies have been shaped by the way
colonialism have been ended, as well as the character of the nationalist governments
that took over state power. Both have somehow adopted, or were forced to adopt,
generally market-oriented land policies, although Zimbabwe started to break away
from this framework when the Mugabe government launched its ‘fast-track’ stateinstigated
land redistribution campaign beginning in 1996. Sam Moyo (Zimbabwe) as
well as Jan Kees van Donge and George Eiseb (Namibia) examine the evolution of
the pro-market land policies and their impact on poverty and social exclusion. They
critically analyze the continuing legacy of colonialism far beyond the formal end of
colonialism as manifested partly in the persistent control over vast tracts of land by
white settlers of European origin.
Historical contextualization of the emergence of varying types of agrarian
structures within countries, as done in each of the country case study in this study, is
important towards a better understanding of land-based social relations and statesociety
interactions around land policies. However, examining land policies in a
global level is equally relevant and important towards a fuller understanding of the
broader and longer historical context within which land reforms appeared,
disappeared and reappeared in the development policy agendas. This will be discussed
in the succeeding section.
Revisiting Past Land Reforms
The terms ‘land reform’ and ‘agrarian reform’ are commonly interchanged to mean
the same thing, i.e. to reform existing agrarian structure. However, some scholars find
it useful to distinguish these terms, i.e. land reform pertains to the reform of the
distribution of landed property rights, while agrarian reform refers to land reform and
complementary socio-economic and political reforms (see, e.g. Thiesenhusen, 1989:
7-9). By making this distinction, analysts hoped that by highlighting this fact it would
3
draw the attention of policy makers to the importance of these complementary
measures for improving the chances of success of the reform sector. In this paper, we
are aware of this distinction, although we will use the two terms interchangeably.
Cycles of land reforms had been carried out in many parts of the world during
the distant past. In its varying forms and scale, land reform was carried out during the
ancient times, beginning with the Greeks and Romans. Much later, the French
Revolution ushered in the era of modern types of land reform after the ancient regime
and feudalism were overthrown in that country. Major land reforms were also carried
out in many parts of Europe, including Russia where, prior to the 1917 Bolshevik
assumption of state power, at least two significant land reform initiatives were carried
out. But it was the past century that witnessed the most numerous land reforms in
human history, starting with the 1910 Mexican revolution. Prior to World War II, land
reform was also implemented in the communist Union of Soviet Socialist Republics
(USSR) where the role of land reform and peasants in the broader industrial
development was hotly debated in the 1920s and early 1930s. Land reform became a
favoured policy by most countries immediately after World War II, a condition that
lasted for a few decades, decisively ending in the early 1980s.4 The reasons for
carrying out land reforms had been varied between and within nations during the
period of 1940s-1980s, although two dominant categories could be noted, namely,
economic and socio-political reasons.
Economic Reasons
The economic basis for land reform was quite powerful an imperative for many of
these initiatives. This is founded on the interlinked assumptions that large farms
under-utilize land, while small farms are wasteful of labour, resulting in low level of
land and labour productivity and consequently leading to poverty.5 Many agrarian
settings are marked by significant degrees of unemployment and under-employment
of labour and relative scarcity of land. Hence, from an economic perspective, it is
sensible to raise land productivity than to try to increase labour productivity.6 There
were no major disagreements among scholars on the issue that many of the preexisting
large farms were generally inefficient and needed restructuring, although the
main pre-occupation that underpinned debates on land reform then was the question
of national economic development. It is on the question of strategic perspective, i.e.
what type of development paradigm land reform is to serve or be taken to, or to what
developmental end should the rural surplus be made to serve, that positions diverge.
This has direct relationship to the closely linked debate on what type of organization
of production should be adopted, i.e. individual or collective farms.
4 Some works that provide relevant crossnational and historical overviews include Tuma (1965), Jones
(1991), King (1977), Tai (1974), Christodoulou (1990), Jacoby (1971), Prosterman, Temple and
Hanstad (1990), Warriner (1969), Paige (1975), Moore (1967), and Sobhan (1993). For recent
conceptual and methodological discussion about comparative studies in land reform, see Borras (2006).
5 Refer, for example, to the influential study edited by Barraclough (1973) in the case of Latin
America. But see Johnston (forthcoming) for fresh arguments on labour-related issues in the land
reform debate.
6 Refer to the discussions by Berry and Cline (1979), Barraclough and Domike (1966), Dorner and
Kanel (1971). For more recent discussion on the economic basis see Binswanger and Deininger (1997,
1996) and Deininger and Binswanger (1999).
4
Through time, and amidst rich theoretical exchanges and practical
experiences, diverse conceptual positions and empirical insights were put forward,
revolving around the contentious issues of the role of agriculture in national
development, ideological frameworks, and types of organization of production,
among others.7 There are however two persistently dominant positions. On the one
side, there is the position that land reform should eventually take the course of the
industrial-urban path to national development, generally favouring a more collectivist
type of land reform,8 and on the other side, the agriculture-rural path to development,
generally favouring a land reform that promotes individual small family farms.9
Moreover and not altogether de-linked from the above-mentioned dichotomy, land
reforms during the past century were also divided by their ideological perspectives,
namely, capitalist- or socialist-oriented, although each camp is quite diverse. Broadly,
in the former, land reform was used to develop private property rights further as a key
institution in capitalist development, while in the latter land reform was used to
liquidate private property rights to strengthen a socialist development largely driven
by the state.10
In most non-socialist settings, the types of organization of production that
were created during and after land reform were very much determined by the
character of pre-existing agrarian structure. It was mainly the collectivist types of land
reform communities that emerged in much of Latin America partly because of the
character of pre-existing landholdings where large farmholdings were directly
operated by landlords and where the contribution by peasants was mainly labour. In
general, individual family farms emerged in East Asian land reforms partly because
the pre-reform farms were smaller and were usually under sharecropping
arrangements with tenant-farmers.
Meanwhile, in most socialist settings, two types of organizations of the reform
sector came into being: state farms and collective/cooperative farms – and these were
determined largely by both the conditions prior to the revolutionary take over of farms
as well as the strategic developmental goals and approaches of the socialist central
state. In some cases, the socialist state just took over plantations from corporate
owners, foreign and domestic, recruited workers and continued the operation of these
new state farms. In other cases, the state expropriated lands and redistributed them to
peasants who were in turn organized into cooperatives. In Cuba after the revolution of
1959, both forms of land expropriation and organization of farms occurred, although
state farms predominated (Ghai, Kay and Peek, 1988). However, in the 1990s, the
pre-existing organizations of production have started to be transformed, especially
affecting state farms which have been broken up into smaller landholdings that are
operated through cooperatives with aspirations for greater production and marketing
efficiency (Deere, 2000).
7 Refer, for example, to the relevant insights offered by Lehmann (1974), Harriss (1982), Ghose
(1983a), Ghimire (2001), Kay (2002), Karshenas (2004), and Wuyts (1994).
8 Refer, for example, to Byres (1974); and more recently, Byres (2004a, 2004b) and Bernstein (2004,
2003, 2002).
9 Refer, for example, to Lipton (1974), and more recently, to Griffin, Khan and Ickowitz (2002).
10 For analytic insights in the context of socialist settings in Latin America, Asia and Africa, refer to
FitzGerald (1985) for the Sandinista Nicaraguan case, Saith (1985) for the Chinese case, O’Laughlin
(1996, 1995) for the case of Mozambique, Abate and Kiros (1983) for the Ethiopian case, and Fagan,
Deere and Corragio (1986) for transnational, comparative perspective.
5
While it may seem that the forms of organizations that emerged out of land
reforms in both capitalist and socialist settings were clustered neatly either as state or
privately owned, individual or collectivist, in reality, the situations were diverse.
Peasants subverted or revised the, or acquiesced to, state-imposed membership to
cooperatives or collectives,11 individual farmers joined together for purposes of
achieving economies of scale in input and output markets, land rights were rented out
and sold despite legal ban on such, workers’ efficiency levels fluctuated in statecontrolled
industrial farming complexes, mechanization was developed in some
places and not in others, and so on – with overall effect resulting in almost always
unintended and unexpected outcomes of official policies.
Socio-Political Reasons
But while the economic basis of land reform was a crucial reason for carrying out
land reform, a variety of socio-political imperatives had in fact and on most
occasions, provided the critical push for such policies to be adopted and implemented
by national governments. There were at least six interlinked broad types of sociopolitical
reasons. First, on the eve of and immediately after World War II, the
decolonization process spread like a praire fire in much of what used to be called
Third World. Land reform became an integral component of these processes in many
national settings, such as in Algeria and Egypt, where emerging nationalist
governments took over colonial lands and distributed these, or some of these, to their
landless rural citizens. The decolonization process continued into the late 1950s until
the 1970s in some remaining former colonies where, to varying extent, land reform
also found its way into the main agenda of the nationalist governments that emerged,
such as in Indonesia with the Basic Agrarian Law of 1960 and Zimbabwe with its
land reform of 1980.12
Second, geo-political and ideological imperatives in the context of the buildup
towards and during the Cold War provided crucial context and reason for the rise
of land reform in the international and national policy agendas. The post-war
‘division’ of the world into the capitalist and socialist blocks had made the United
States rush to consolidate its ideological and political hold in East Asia which was
fronting the vast territories of the communist USSR and China. Land reform was a
key component in the American consolidation of this region, where it imposed and
financed sweeping land reforms in Japan, South Korea and Taiwan partly in reaction
to the revolutionary land reform being carried out in China.13 The subsequent Cold
War became an arena where the capitalist and socialist ideological perspectives
battled against each other on different contentious themes, among which was the
question of how to address the issue of rural poverty, through what type of land
reform, and within what broader development framework. As communist- and
socialist-inspired national liberation movements gained ground, some of which being
11 See James Scott (1998) for an insightful overview account of farm mechanization in the USSR in the
1920s-1930s, as well as in the efforts to construct modern socialist farms and villages in Tanzania and
Ethiopia in the 1970s-1980s.
12 See Tsing (2002) for an historical analysis of the promulgation and subsequent implications of the
Agrarian Law of 1960 in Indonesia. Refer to Bratton (1990) for the historical background and initial
implementation of the Zimbabwean land reform.
13 Of course there are other important reasons, both internal and external to these countries, for carrying
out land reform other than in reaction to the communist threat from China and the USSR. For varying
analysis, see Kay (2002), Griffin, Khan and Ickowitz (2002), Tai (1974), and King (1977).
6
able to seize state power, the capitalist block took on the agenda of land reform with
greater ideological vigour and sense of political urgency. American agents led by
Wolf Ladejinsky crisscrossed the world to pressure national governments to carry out
(a capitalist version of) ‘pre-emptive’ land reform (see Walinsky, 1977; Ross, 1998,
Chp. 5; Putzel, 1992). Towards this end, the US instigated the formation of the
Alliance for Progress in Latin America and the Caribbean in the 1960s where land
reform took a center-stage in the alliance’s agenda. In short, land reform was used by
the two contending camps as key policy ammunition (and shield) during the Cold
War.
Third, land reform also became crucial component of national projects of
victorious peasant-based revolutions. The prominence of land reform in this context is
due partly to the fact that the demand for land by peasants was quite strongly
internalized within the revolutionary government. But its prominence was also partly
due to the revolutionary government’s desire to consolidate its political legitimacy
and to quell possible reactionary counter-revolution on the one hand, and the central
state’s need to proceed with its developmental project that would be financed to a
significant extent by ‘squeezing’ agriculture of surplus factors of production. It was in
this context that land reforms emerged and were implemented in Mexico, Bolivia,
Nicaragua, and Vietnam (Tannenbaum, 1929; Grindle, 1986; Collins, Lappè and
Allen, 1982; Paige, 1975; Wolf, 1969). The Guatemalan land reform emerged in a
similar context, but it was a case that saw immediate reversal through a counterrevolution
(see Handy, 1994).
Fourth, in reaction to external and internal political pressure, land reform was
used by central states to ‘manage’ rural unrest. While some of such rural unrests were
communist-inspired, many should be seen as parts of ongoing cycles of peasant revolt
against unjust and exploitative conditions, and their struggles for social justice, as in
the cases of the Huk and Mau-Mau rebellions in the Philippines and Kenya. The
conflagration of forcible land occupations, often met with violence from state and
nonstate actors, that marked the countryside of many countries after the Second
World War, such as those in Peru, the Philippines, northern Mexico, Indonesia (see,
Wolf, 1969; Stavenhagen, 1971; Hobsbawm, 1974; Landsberger, 1974; Kerkvliet,
1993; Huizer, 2001; Kay, 2001; Redclift, 1978), and even in Italy, Portugal and
southern Spain, unsettled national governments. The subsequent patches of successful
regional land redistribution outcomes within these countries were testimonies of the
effort of central states to respond, albeit selectively and partially, to these pockets of
rural unrest.
Fifth, in other cases, land reform was used to legitimize and/or consolidate the
claim to state power by one faction of the elite against another. This happened
immediately after military take over of state power, like in Peru in the late 1960s,
where the new government tried to debase possible elite challengers by expropriating
their landholdings and to court popular support by redistributing lands to peasants
(Kay, 1983), or in the Philippines during the Marcos authoritarian regime (Putzel,
1992; Riedinger, 1995). This also happened when Left political parties gained
7
electoral victories, such as those in Chile in the early 1970s (Castillo and Lehmann,
1983), as well as in the states of Kerala and West Bengal in India.14
Finally, land reform was used by the central state in its continuing statebuilding
process. Land reform, and the usually accompanying land titling and
colonization programs, required systematic and standardized cadastral maps, land
titles, and peasant household registration, and so on. These in turn feed into the need
of the central state to extend its administrative, political and military-police presence
and authority into the more remote parts of its claimed territory, as well as into the
need of the central state to develop its tax base. Taken altogether, these processes
form part of the central state’s effort, in the words of James Scott (1998), to ‘simplify’
and render ‘legible’ the otherwise numerous complex social relationships in ‘non-state
spaces’.
Different land reforms were passed into law, implemented, and resulted in
varied and uneven outcomes between and within countries over time. Some land
reforms redistributed more lands, either collectively or individually, to more peasant
households than others, such as those in Cuba, China, Japan, South Korea, Kerala,
Bolivia, Taiwan, Peru and Mexico on the one side, and Venezuela, Brazil, Bangladesh
and Pakistan on the other side. Some of the land reforms that were able to redistribute
significant quantities of land to a significant number of agricultural households
actually led to substantial reduction in rural poverty, such as those in South Korea and
Cuba, although other countries in the same category did not witness any significant
rural poverty reduction, as in Bolivia. Moreover, the countries that carried out
significant land reform and where the state provided massive direct and indirect
support in the input and output markets of the rural economy, as well as in pro-poor
social policies (e.g. health, education), were able to reduce rural poverty quite
dramatically, as in the cases of Japan, Taiwan, China, Cuba, and Kerala. Meanwhile,
the countries that had important land reforms but whose national governments failed
to carry out massive and sustained support in the input and output markets for the
reformed rural sectors were unable to radically reduce the level of poverty in their
countryside, as in the case of Bolivia and Mexico.15
Furthermore, five issues relevant to the discussion above are to be noted. First,
none of the various competing brands of and approaches to land reform had the
monopoly of cases that resulted in widespread land redistribution and poverty
eradication. Second, in general land reforms were carried out in many developing
countries amidst the dominant ‘protectionist’, ‘inward-looking’ development
strategies developed and promoted by countries in the socialist block as well as those
in the capitalist world. Land reform had become an integral component of these
inward-looking, protectionist policies for a variety of reasons, including the central
state’s aspiration to create a domestic market for its industrial sector (see, e.g. Kay,
2002; Wuyts, 1994). It is not surprising therefore that the peak period of the Import-
Substitution Industrialization (ISI) was also the era of land reformism in many
14 See various analyses by Raj and Tharakan (1983), Ghose (1983b), Herring (1983), Banerjee, Getler
and Ghatak (2002), Harriss (1993), Baruah (1990), and Lieten (1996).
15 Important crossnational comparative studies, albeit from varying perspectives and disciplines,
include de Janvry (1981), de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989), Thiesenhusen (1989, 1995), Dorner (1992),
Kay (1998, 2004) for Latin America; Herring (1983) and Tai (1974) for Asia; and more generally:
Ghose (1983a), Tuma (1965), Sobhan (1993), Christodoulou (1990), King (1977).
8
countries. The timing of land reform in the context of a country’s industrialization
drive can be very crucial and may have direct bearing on the probability of success in
land redistribution as well as in post-land redistribution national development, as for
example, in the contrasting cases of Latin America and East Asia (Kay, 2002). Third,
some of these land reforms were later subjected to counter-reform where, to varying
extents, previously redistributed lands, or portion of these, were returned to the
previous owners and other sectors close to the new status quo. In varying
circumstances and extents of reform reversal, Guatemala, Chile and Nicaragua share
this similar experience. Fourth, most of the land reforms, but especially the capitalistoriented
ones, while they involved significant degree of state initiative and
intervention, had also witnessed the significant roles played by non-state actors –
peasant movements and their allies. These issues bring us to the question of policy
and political strategies of carrying out land reform, a topic that occupies an important
portion of the current discourse on land policies.
Different land reforms were implemented by state and non-state actors through
different political strategies between and within countries over time. Some were
implemented through varying strands of centralized authoritarian methods, such as in
many East Asian land reforms (Tai, 1974), China and Peru, while others were
implemented through more ‘democratic’ approaches, as in the cases of Kerala and
West Bengal in India (Herring, 1983). While some analysts would present a
dichotomy marked by ‘state-led’ on the one side, and ‘peasant-led’ on the other (see,
e.g. de Janvry, Sadoulet and Wolford, 2001), it may be more useful to look at these
political processes within an ‘interactive state/society’ perspective because resolving
claims and counter-claims for property rights involves not only a peasant-state
relationship, but also those within the state and between different groups in society
(Borras, 2001; Herring, 1983; Fox, 1993, 2004). The interactive state/society
framework seems to offer better analytic lens to explain political processes in land
reform whether in single party-ruled socialist countries such as in China during the
first wave of communist land reform in the early 1950s (Shillinglaw, 1974), or
politically open countries with ruling communist/socialist parties that implemented
land reform, as in Chile under Allende, or in West Bengal and Kerala in India (Kay
and Silva, 1992; Ghose, 1983b). In these cases, land reform implementation relied on
the ruling parties and the central state to implement land reform, but these political
parties and the central state, in turn, relied heavily on the mobilization of the rural
masses to actually implement land reform and make it work. Meanwhile, land reforms
that were implemented in capitalist-oriented, open political settings, relied to a large
extent on the autonomy and capacity of the central state to carry out its promise of and
mandate for land reform. But the central state in turn relied mainly on the support and
mobilization of the affected rural population (Barraclough, 2001). In many settings, of
course, the state simply took the lead from the peasants who unilaterally occupied
lands, forcing the central state to legitimize such actions, as in the case of the Bolivian
land reform of 1953 (Urioste, 2001).
The 1980s Interregnum
Meanwhile, in the 1980s, land reform had had an abrupt and heavy fall from grace. It
was eliminated from official development policy agendas of international institutions
and nation states. While in most cases nation states did not actually pass new laws to
9
stop or halt land reforms, many of them decided to place existing land reform laws
and policies in dormant status: land reform laws continue to exist at least officially,
but no significant funds were allotted to nor administrative machineries set up or
maintained for their implementation. In short, there was no ‘political will’ to
implement the land reform law. The cases of land reform laws in Indonesia (Wiradi,
2005) and Bolivia are examples of this. It was in this historical juncture that the
broadly pro-market land policy reforms would find its seeds. The subsequent
paradigm shift in terms of land reform occurred due to various factors, or the
convergence of such factors, as will be discussed below.
Among such factors is the debt crisis that started in the early 1980s that
crippled the fiscal capabilities of national governments of most developing countries
and slowed down their economic growth and development. The subsequent rise of
neoliberalism and its advocacy to cutback public spending and at the same time to
raise taxes largely in order to pay off debts or just to scale down if not stop borrowing
altogether pushed land reform out of the official agenda of many national
governments because it is a policy that required substantial state financing including
regular appropriation to maintain a huge bureaucracy, while at the same time it is
believed to erode some sections of pre-existing tax base.16
Second, the economic crisis of agriculture in general,17 and the land reform
sector in particular, that included widespread social discontent about the ‘actually
existing’ land reforms, both in socialist and capitalist settings, forced governments
and external development agencies to introduce varying forms and degrees of
adjustments. In some socialist countries as well as in capitalist settings that resorted to
collectivist land reform, experiments on (state and) collective farms usually did not
result in the intended gains in production and productivity levels, both for the
households and for the purposes of national development campaigns. These farm
collectives were also hounded by the persistent problem of rent-seeking activities by
state officials and farm collective leaders. These conditions provided constant
pressure for de-collectivization, which was eventually matched by the central state’s
eagerness to rescind on their responsibility on the (economic) performance of the
reformed sector.
Third, beginning in the 1970s, technological advancement directly and
indirectly related to agriculture gained more ground: more fertilizer and pesticide use,
proliferation of improved seeds and high-yield varieties, farm mechanization, relative
improvement in physical infrastructure in the rural areas such as road, irrigation and
electrification – the Green revolution package of technology. There were optimistic
celebrations about the prospects of eradicating rural poverty and hunger via
technological innovation. While in some instances, both in policy discourse and in
actual practice, technological advancement and land reform were not seen to
contradict each other, the rise in significance of technological advancement in the
input and output markets of agriculture gave additional incentive for modernizing,
16 The general analytic insights found in Gwynne and Kay (2004) offer relevant views that put this
issue in a better historical and broader context. Refer also to Spoor (1997).
17 For a critical reflection on the performance of agriculture during the much-maligned period prior to
neoliberalism, refer to Spoor (2002) for a specific study of the Latin American experience.
10
entrepreneurially minded landlords to resist land reform, and provided governments
less politically contentious policy alternatives toward rural poverty reduction.18
Fourth, in the 1980s, especially toward the later part of that decade, most
communist- and socialist-inspired national liberation movements had been waning,
with others completely dissipated, for various internal and external reasons. The
conflagration of unrest manifested in peasant land occupations that marked much of
the rural world in the 1950s through the 1970s was not immediately visible during this
decade. From a distance, there was relative silence and calm. Of course one reason for
this was the demobilization of previously militant mass of peasants after they received
lands from the state land reform programs during the preceding decade or two. The
relative absence of visible forms of significant peasant unrest and militancy in the
rural areas during this decade helped encourage national governments to place land
reforms in their dormant status if not completely taken out of the official agenda.
Finally, the end of the Cold War towards the later part of the 1980s signaled
some form of closure of the ideological rivalry between socialist versus capitalist
paths to development. There was a general perception that there was no more
immediate communist and socialist threat to the capitalist world, and so, there was no
more urgent need for ‘Ladejinskys’ to crisscross the world to promote pre-emptive
land reforms. In the 1980s, restructuring of property rights and farm work incentive
structure in state and collective farms were slowly introduced in countries that would
later be labeled collectively as ‘transitional economies’. These reforms have been
broadly market-oriented, giving the individuals and households more flexibility in
some bundles of landed property rights and providing them greater control over their
farm surplus and on how to dispose them. But it would only be in the 1990s, after the
decisive collapse of the actually existing socialism in Eastern Europe, that such
market-oriented reforms would gain enormous ground (see, e.g. Akram Lodhi, 2005;
Spoor, 2003; Deere, 2000).
These six factors, separately and jointly, have adversely impacted on land
reform, resulting in the latter’s decisive exclusion from the official development
agendas. This policy elimination had been carried out with relative ease because of
the ‘checkered’ record of land reform, especially in terms of its declared goal on
poverty eradication – and, arguably, because those that wanted land reform out of the
official development policy agenda were successful in waging hegemonic policy
discourse, projecting land reform as a ‘failure’ especially in terms of eradicating
poverty in the countryside (see Borras, 2003b).
The Resurrection and ‘Metamorphosis’ of Land Reform in the 1990s Onwards
In the 1990s, however, land reform was resurrected in the development policy
agendas of international development institutions as well as in many nation states. It
was a confluence of events and convergence of factors that put land back in the
development policy agendas.
18 For insightful analysis of the changing political-economy of global food regimes, the invention and
proliferation of the Green Revolution ideology and how, in different ways and to varying extents, these
impacted on the land question in most developing countries during this period, refer to Lappé, Collins
and Rosset (1998), Friedmann (2005), Boyce (1993), and Ross (1998).
11
First, around the mid-1990s, pockets of dramatic land-based political conflicts
caught the attention of the world. Three of these were most important, namely, the
Chiapas uprising in southern Mexico, the state-instigated land invasions by black
landless poor of white commercial farms in Zimbabwe, and the resurgence of militant
peasant land occupations in Brazil reminiscent of the actions by the peasant leagues of
the 1950s but much greater in scale and political sophistication (Harvey, 1998; Moyo,
2000; Moyo and Yeros, 2005; Ghimire, 2005; Petras, 1998, 1997; Veltmeyer, 2005,
1997; Wright and Wolford, 2003; Meszaros, 2000; Bradford and Rocha, 2002).
National governments were compelled to address these boiling social pressures ‘from
below’, while the international development community grappled with the meanings
and implications of such complex conflicts, resulting in the convergence of
international and national efforts to address these land-based grievances. But these
resurgent peasant mobilizations occurred also in many other places, such as in the
Philippines, Honduras, Bolivia, South Africa and Indonesia, although these did not
get the same scale and extent of inter(national) media attention than the three cases
cited above.19 Altogether, these phenomena validate what Ronald Herring (2003)
observed, that land reform was taken out of the ‘policy agendas’ of national
governments and international agencies, but it never left the ‘political agendas’ of
peasants and their organizations. Herring explained that even ‘dead land reforms are
not dead; they become nodes around which future peasant mobilizations emerge
because promises unkept keep movements alive.’ It is also important to note that these
peasant actions have been broadened in many parts of the world by mobilizations for
land and democratic rights by indigenous peoples, such as those in Bolivia and
Ecuador (see, e.g. Yashar, 1999, 2005; Korovkin, 2000) and by peasant women (see,
e.g. Razavi, 2003), as well as by the urban poor in countries like Brazil and South
Africa. These changed contexts and sets of actors have also transformed the
perceptions about land reform and rural livelihoods (Gwynne and Kay, 2004),
facilitating the emergence of (new) sets of policy agendas, such as renewed efforts in
land titling and cadastral records that would subsequently attract greater development
policy and academic interests (Zoomers and van der Haar, 2000; Kay, 1998).
Second, in some countries ravaged by political conflict, negotiated settlements
or regime transitions occurred, where the question of solving poverty and social
exclusion was made part of the peace-building processes or democratic
(re)constructions, especially those in the countryside.20 Hence, for example, land
reform was resurrected in the official agenda of the El Salvadorean government as
part of its post-conflict peace-building process (Foley, 1997; Pearce, 1998; Diskin,
1989). The same was attempted a few years back in Colombia, although without
much success in terms of sustaining it in the official agenda (Ross, 2003). Moreover,
it was within post-authoritarian regime transition context that land reforms were
resurrected in the official policy agendas in the mid-1980s in Brazil and the
Philippines (see Fox, 1990; Houtzager, 2000; Franco, 2001; Riedinger, 1995). It was
19 Refer for example to Franco and Borras (2005), Urioste (2001), Greenberg (2004), and Lucas and
Warren (2003), respectively.
20 See also Pons-Vignon and Lecomte (2004). It is also within this broad context that we should
understand the renewed calls for land reform during the many regime transitions when, for various
reasons, centralized authoritarian regimes in many developing countries collapsed and political
processes for greater (rural) democratization gained some ground (see, e.g. the edited volume on rural
democratization by Fox, 1990).
12
also in the same context that the land reform agenda took prominence in the postapartheid
South Africa, where, alongside the adopted policies of land distribution and
leasehold reform, the policy of land restitution was officially inaugurated.21 It is also
in this similar context that the heated land policy debate erupted in post-dictatorship
Indonesia (Lucas and Warren, 2003; Aspinal, 2004).
Third, beginning in the early 1990s, when several countries abandoned
socialism, they were confronted by the difficult question of what to do with the huge
state and collective farms. The challenge of sensible transition in these farms has put
the question of landed property rights among the top policy agendas of concerned
national governments and international development institutions (see Deininger, 1995,
2002; Spoor, 2003; Spoor and Visser, 2004). Also, other socialist countries, as
mentioned earlier, started to adjust the incentive structure in their agricultural sector,
ushering in a new era of varying forms and bundles of land-based property rights and
market exchange in several socialist countries (see, e.g., Akram Lodhi, 2004, 2005;
Kerkvliet, 2005, 1994, for Vietnam).
Finally, the rise of neoliberalism and its aspiration to achieve a complete
ideological hegemony in all aspects of development question and initiative has
brought the issue of land under a new – but different – spotlight. The problems with
the earlier neoliberal policy prescriptions became more apparent in the late 1980s,
particularly the inherent limits and flaws of income-centred and growth-oriented
approaches to poverty eradication and development. The persistent poverty and
growing inequality have put into question the neoliberal paradigm. The emergence of
this problem forced mainstream economists to introduce adjustments to their
development policy model. It is in this context where the issue of poor people’s
access to productive assets, including land, was (re)introduced. The assumption is that
poor people are poor because they do not have access to productive resources. Closely
linked to this is the popularization of the notion of ‘insecurity’ in the context of rural
livelihoods and economic investments in the countryside. The consensus among
mainstream economists was that many rural poor people have insecure access to land
resources, leading to their unstable livelihoods and low level of investments. The
imperative of developing formal private and individualized landed property rights
through land titling programs in public lands, as well as land sales and rental
arrangements in private lands have thus become more urgent and necessary. It has
been popularly assumed that these property rights-related campaigns will not only
make poor people’s access to land secure, but it will also make financial investments
in the rural economy more attractive (see Deininger and Binswanger, 1999; World
Bank, 2003, 2005). Furthermore, the interest on land and on the institutional
regulations about its ownership, control and use is also linked to the efforts of
transnational corporate sector, especially those engaged in agro-food business and
timber sector, to expand their production (and trade) hegemony in developing
countries and transition economies (see Friedmann, 2005; Goodman and Watts, 1997;
McMichael, 1995; Magdoff, Buttel, and Foster, 1998; Lappé, Collins and Rosset,
1998; van den Hombergh, 2004). And so, land was rushed back onto the development
policy agendas of mainstream international development institutions, and then rechanneled
widely to national government agencies, and even to NGOs.
21 For critical analyses, see Levin and Weiner (1997), Bernstein (1998), Lahiff (2003), and Cousins
(1997).
13
Altogether, the four factors and events have put land back onto the official
development policy discourses and agendas. However, the content and context of the
policy revival are significantly different from those of the past land reform policy
initiatives. The terms of the current policy discourse on land is dominated by the
broadly pro-market mainstream economists. The previous, ideologically grounded
debates around ‘capitalist- versus socialist-oriented’, ‘individualist versus collectivist’
land reforms were now supplanted by the new discourses propagated by those who
rejected the conventional notion of expropriationary land reform. And so we are
currently confronted by debate formulations such as: ‘state- versus market-led’,
‘coercive versus voluntary’, ‘centralized versus decentralized’, or ‘top-down/supplydriven
versus bottom-up/demand-driven’ land reforms (see Borras, 2003a, 2003b).22
Instead of uncritically accepting these presented dichotomies, we take such
constructions as problematic.
Moreover, among the ongoing land reforms diversity in approach is apparent:
from ‘state-instigated’ as in Zimbabwe (Palmer, 2000b; Moyo, 2000; Worby 2001), to
‘peasant-led’ as in Brazil (Wright and Wolford, 2003; Wolford, 2003; Rosset, 2001;
Petras, 1998), to ‘state/society-driven’ as in the Philippines (Borras, 2001; Franco,
2005), to ‘market-led’, as in some pilot programs in Colombia, Brazil, South Africa
and the Philippines (Deininger, 1999). It is thus important to examine from a
comparative perspective the ongoing land reforms in different parts of the world,
highlighting both their similarities and differences; this research undertaking aspires
to contribute toward this effort by drawing lessons from the discussion of the ten
country cases.
In short, past land reforms despite their diversity in ideological provenance
and orientation, had been united on several common economic and socio-political
themes. Nevertheless, past land reform discourse and practice also missed, to a
significant degree, a number of issues now considered as crucial to the success or
failure of land reform itself, and of any broad-based sustainable development more
generally. The way different development issues, broadly categorized as economic
and socio-political, have become important contexts for and objects of land reforms,
has been altered over time, as shown in Table 1. If we take a simplified periodization
of pre-1980s and post-1990s land reforms (with the 1980s as an ‘interregnum’), then
we would see that many old issues have remained relevant and important up to this
time, while others have in varying degrees waned in importance or even disappeared.
Still, many development issues that are not critical in the past have emerged to be
important issues at present, and certainly, in the future, as in the cases of gender,
indigenous peoples, violence, and the environment. While land reforms were
admittedly treated as integral component of broad development strategies whose
strategic aims eventually included eradicating poverty, in general the relationship
between land reform and poverty reduction were more theoretically assumed than
empirically demonstrated.
22 It is broadly within this context that decentralized approaches to natural resources management have
become very important in development policy discourse – for critical studies, refer to Ribot ad Larson
(2005).
14
Table 1: Changes in the Economic and Socio-Political Bases of, and Imperatives for, Land
Reforms
___________________________________________________________________________
Pre-1980s Period 1990s Onward
Economic
Existing large landed estates are economically Continuing relevance/currency
inefficient; must be re-structured via land reform
Creation of privatized & individualized landed Continuing – and has seen greater expansion in coverage
property rights to boost investments in rural economy
Issues related to inefficiency (& accountability) in (former) socialist state
farms & cooperatives, e.g. Eastern Europe, central Asia, Vietnam, China
Issues related to efficiency in farm collectives brought about by past land
reforms, e.g. Mexico & Peru
Socio-Political
De-colonization While to a large extent it is not a burning issue with the same intensity as
decades ago, decolonization process-related issues have persisted in
many countries, such as Zimbabwe
Cold War Not anymore
Central state’s ‘management’ of rural unrest Diminished substantially as liberation movements waned. But rural
usually instigated by liberation movements unrest persisted usually not in the context of armed groups wanting to
for revolutionary societal/state transformation seize state power but to push for radical reforms, e.g. Chiapas, Brazil
As a strategy to legitimize and/or consolidate Continuing, e.g. Zimbabwe, tenancy reform by the Left Front in West
one elite faction’s hold on to state power against Bengal
another, e.g. Left electoral victories, military
coup d’ etat.
As an integral component of the central state’s Continuing, and has seen unprecedented degree of technological
of ‘modernization’, i.e. standardized cadastral sophistication (e.g. satellite/digital mapping, computerized data-banking)
maps, etc. for taxation purposes, etc.
i) Post-conflict democratic construction and consolidation, e.g. postapartheid
South Africa, post-civil war El Salvador (Pearce, 1998; Foley,
1997), Colombia (Ross, 2003)
ii) Advancement of knowledge about the distinct rights of indigenous
peoples (e.g. Yashar, 1999, 2005; Korovkin, 2000)
iii) Advancement of knowledge about gender-land rights issues, see, e.g.
Razavi (2003); Agarwal (1994), Kabeer (1995); Deere (1985), and Deere
and León (2001)
iv) Greater concern about the environment (see, e.g. Herring, 2002)
v) Persistence and resurgence of violence related to drugs and ethnic
issues (see, e.g. Pons-Vignon and Lecomte, 2004)
vi) Emerging ‘[human] rights-based approaches’ to development
vii) The phenomenal rise of NGOs as important actor in development
question at the local, national and international levels
_____________________________________________________________________
When land reform was resurrected in development policy discourse beginning
in the 1990s, it has undergone a metamorphosis, at least as far as the dominant groups
in the academic and policy practitioner’s circles are concerned. The neoliberal
paradigm on land policies is the dominant current in today’s development policy
discourse and practice. These land policies have been conceptualized and promoted
15
within a changed global, national and local context. Development strategies changed
from ‘protectionist and inward-looking perspective’, to ‘free trade and outwardlooking
orientation’, or from state-directed to market-oriented. The land policies that
have emerged in the 1990s, and the various meanings and purposes accorded to these
by different competing groups, should be seen as integral component of these
processes of global neoliberal reforms.23
These land policies have been theorized for and carried out in four broad types
of settings. First, ‘public and/or communal’ lands are chief targets for privatization.
Mainstream economic policies are arguing and advocating for the systematic
privatization and individualization of property rights in public/communal lands in
order to transform these land resources into active capital. Thus, renewed interest and
initiatives at land titling, registration and (decentralized land) administration have
seen unprecedented level and extent.24 The current efforts are different from past
initiatives on at least two counts: i) the scale in terms of spaces being covered, or are
being aspired to be covered, is enormous and unprecedented, and ii) the degree of
technical sophistication in terms of (satellite/digital) mapping and (computerized)
data-banking has been unparalleled in human history. Moreover, while the
mainstream policies at times recognize the relevance of pre-existing communal forms
of property ownership, they nevertheless advocate for individualized property rights
within these blocks of common landed properties, e.g. individual plots where the right
to use can be freely traded (World Bank, 2003). This policy, aimed at homogenizing
property rights regimes across diverse national and subnational settings, is currently
being implemented through various policies and projects, with varied outcomes.25
Second, state and collective farms, both in capitalist settings and in
‘transitional economies,’ are also important targets for farm privatization and
parcelization. Mainstream economists believe that collective farms established in
settings where significant capitalist-oriented land reforms were implemented in the
past had produced institutions that have hampered, not promoted, incentives for
individuals to become economically efficient and competitive farmers, and have
impeded the emergence of more fluid land market. Thus, they have advocated for the
privatization and individualization of property rights in these farms, as key incentive
for farms to produce more and to produce efficiently. This is the case, for example, in
Mexico and Peru. Moreover, and for broadly similar reasons, the policy of
privatization and individualization of state collective farms in transitional economies
were also advocated and (unevenly) carried out in different countries (Deininger,
1995; Spoor, 2003). The initial outcomes are varied between countries: it does not
seem to have the intended outcome of vibrant land markets in the reformed
(privatized-parcelized) ejidos in Mexico (Nuijten, 2003) for example, although it
23 See, for example, the argument advanced by Fortin (2005) in the specific context of Sub-Saharan
Africa, and Bush (2002) in the context of Egypt.
24 The mainstream arguments for such renewed efforts on land titling, registration and related policies
are captured quite clearly by Bryant (1996); see also de Soto (2000).
25 For preliminary critical studies in the context of Africa, see Toulmin and Quan (2000), Platteau
(1996), Quan (2000), Palmer (2000a), Berry (2002), McAuslan (2000), Matondi and Moyo (2003); for
Latin America, see Jansen and Roquas (1998), Hernaiz, Pacheco, Guerrero and Miranda (2000), and
Zoomers and van der Haar (2000); for a view from Asia, see Borras (forthcoming, 2006).
16
seems to have resulted in increased production and productivity levels, albeit amidst
increasing inequality, in Vietnam (Akram Lodhi, 2005).26
The first two policies discussed so far are directed towards non-private lands –
in order to create private, individualized landed property rights. The discussion that
follows will be on the two policies that are directed towards private lands.
Third, private productive farms are to be reformed only under certain
conditions and within a specific economic orientation. For mainstream economists
and development policy experts one of the reasons of low production and productivity
level in the rural economies is because of the persistence of ‘distortions’ in the land
market where inefficient producers continue to own and control lands while the more
efficient ones (and those that have potential to become efficient producers) could not
access land (World Bank, 2003). These distortions, according to the mainstream view,
are caused by various factors including many land reform-related laws that limit the
land rental and sales transactions in the market. For the mainstream view, the
principal policy for this type of setting is the promotion of non-coercive
sharecropping tenancy reform, through leasehold arrangement. This policy is believed
to be more sensible and practical towards achieving the most economically efficient
land resource use and allocation, and it does not entail any major state fiscal
requirement. It will also contribute to the development of vibrant land market.
Sadoulet, Murgai and de Janvry (2001: 196-97) explain that land markets “have
welfare effects, even though rental is not a transfer of wealth.” They contend that this
is because “in the long-run, access to land via tenancy may help the landless capitalize
the returns to otherwise idle assets [e.g. family labor], accumulate wealth, and move
up an ‘agricultural ladder’ toward land ownership.” Klaus Deininger of the World
Bank’s land policy unit supports this assumption and argues that only in settings
where rental arrangement is not feasible should land reform through land sales be
considered (1999: 666). For the mainstream view, this policy should be carried out
simultaneously with other related policies including those that lift the ‘ceiling’ on land
ownership and ban on land rental and sales, as well as the legal prohibitions on share
tenancy practices (World Bank, 2003; see also Baranyi, Deere and Morales, 2004:
33).
Fourth, same as the third – it pertains to private farms, but with different
policy treatment. The mainstream view still believes that large farms that are
inefficient should be redistributed to tenant-farmers and farmworkers, so that small
family farms that are believed to be more economically efficient can be created. But
the approach in carrying out this reform is quite different from the conventional
framework. This policy aims to substitute the conventional coercive land reform with
a voluntary policy. As mentioned above, the favoured policy toward private farms is
the promotion of share tenancy arrangement; only in circumstances where there are
‘willing sellers’ and ‘willing buyers’ of land should land sales be allowed. The
features of this pro-market ‘land reform’ are, according to its advocates, the opposite
of the features of conventional land reforms: voluntary not coercive, demand-driven
26 Among contemporary scholars who have carried out empirical studies and theorizing on land
markets within an economic perspective, perhaps Michael Carter is among the few who have offered
sophisticated analysis based on his examination of Latin American cases (see, e.g. 2000; Carter and
Salgado, 2001; Carter and Mesbah, 1993). Refer also to the various studies in Zoomers and van der
Haar (2000).
17
not supply-driven, private not state land transactions, decentralized not centralized,
top-down/centralized versus bottom-up/decentralized, and so on. This policy,
popularly known as Market-Led Agrarian Reform (MLAR), is a scheme whereby
landlords are paid 100 percent spot-cash for 100 percent market value of the land,
where the cost of the land transfer is shouldered fully by the buyer; landlords
unwilling to part with their estates will not be coerced to sell their lands (Deininger
and Binswanger, 1999; World Bank, 2003; 2005: 156-175; but see Borras, 2003a,
2003b, 2005; Navarro, 1998).
In varying policy adaptations and scales, this policy model has been
implemented in several countries, such as Brazil, Colombia, South Africa and the
Philippines. Its initial outcomes, or the meanings of these outcomes especially in
terms of reducing poverty and social exclusion in the countryside, are interpreted
differently by different scholars and policy practitioners. For the optimistic claims,
see Buainain et al (1999), Deininger (1999), Deininger and Binswanger (1999); and
for critical insights, see Barros, Sauer and Schwartzman (2003), Sauer (2003), Levin
and Weiner (1997), Lahiff (2003), Lebert (2001), El-Ghonemy (2001), Riedinger,
Yang, and Brook (2001), Reyes (1999), and Borras (2003a, 2003b, 2005).27 This
policy has been actively opposed by several rural-oriented civil society groups,
coordinated internationally by La Via Campesina, the Foodfirst Information and
Action Network or FIAN, and the Land Research and Action Network or LRAN (see
Baranyi, Deere and Morales, 2004; Borras, 2004).
In short, policies in the four broad types of settings are based upon the use of
markets as a principal means of reallocating land resources under formal property
rights that are ‘secure’ so as to entice capital inflow into the rural economy. The
World Bank calls these policies collectively as ‘pro-poor land policies’. The initial
outcomes of these land policies in various countries have been comprehensively
reviewed by the World Bank in its August 2003 Policy Research Report Land
Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. This Report is now an important
document in the formulation of land policies in many developing and transitional
economies, as well as having a major influence on debates around such policies. In
fact, the European Union Council of Ministers approved in November 2004 its own
similar, but not the same, version of a blueprint of land policy guidelines for its
overseas development assistance,28 and so have all other major multilateral and
bilateral development agencies. The framework of this World Bank report has been
reiterated in the World Development Report 2006 (see Chapter 8).
Common Themes and Competing Perspectives
The economic and socio-political imperatives for, bases and impact of, land reforms
are the common themes to all country case studies in this multidisciplinary research
project. These themes are examined not separately from each other, but in relational
way. In this research undertaking, land and landed property rights are treated not
27 For a relevant critical insights based on the experience of southern Mexico, refer to Bobrow-Strain
(2004). Refer also to the critical insights offered by Paasch (2003) and the joint critique put forward by
La Via Campesina and the Foodfirst Information and Action Network or FIAN (FIAN-Via Campesina,
2003).
28 For critical reflections on the European Union (draft) land policy, see Monsalve (2004).
18
merely as factor of economic production, but as a resource that has social, cultural and
political dimensions. Understanding the relationships between these different
dimensions of land and the policies around these necessarily requires a closer
examination of the roles of the ‘free’ market, state, and civil society – and how they
shape one another towards a ‘pro-poor’ (re)allocation of land resources. Each country
case study in this land policy series is analyzed from within this framework.
Viewed from this perspective, the contemporary debate about agrarian reform
is marked by four broadly distinct and competing views about land reform – as
summarized in Table 2.29 The fault-lines between these four are the differences on
what types of land reform and which strategies to employ in order to achieve their
objectives, especially on reducing poverty and social exclusion in the countryside. It
must be noted that these are ideal types. They are useful as analytical typology, but
the reality does not always neatly fit with each type. This typology, in turn, serves as
general analytic signposts for the country studies in this land policy paper series.
The first common theme is the role of ‘free’ markets in the (re)allocation of
land resources between different social classes and groups in society as well as sectors
in the national economy. All the papers in this research project examine whether and
how and to what extent the forces of the ‘free’ market have (re)distributed access to
and control over land resources that favour the rural poor. All the essays critically
examine the empirical materials from the various countries that have been studied
against the backdrop of an existing mainstream assumption about the superiority of
the forces of the ‘free’ market in land resource (re)distribution. As partly explained in
the country case studies in this research project such as the Uzbekistan, Vietnamese
and Armenian cases, this perspective is the one that views land reform as a policy that
can and should facilitate the provision of privatized and individualized property rights
to as many people in as much spaces as possible – through market-led and marketoriented
mechanisms of transferring property rights and of governing land markets.
This is represented by mainstream economists and, to a large extent, by development
policy experts. This perspective does not altogether rule out the role of the state, but
that role is being modified, from being key to a facilitative one, and assigned with the
tasks of: providing the necessary legal institutional frameworks for these market
mechanisms to emerge and operate, providing information accessible to
‘stakeholders’ to create a ‘level playing field’, and promoting transparency and
accountability. The state, especially its local government units, is also required to
promote and enter into ‘partnerships’ with the civil society and private sectors.
Deininger (1999) and World Bank (2003) represent this view.
The second common theme is the role of the state in the ‘pro-poor’
(re)allocation of land resources. All papers in this research undertaking examine how
and to what extent central states played a role in the (re)distribution of land resources
between different social classes and groups in society and between the different
sectors of the economy. All the papers in this research project critically examine the
state and its role in pro-poor land policies partly in dialogue with an existing school of
thought in the agrarian reform literature that identifies the central state as the leading
actor in any pro-poor redistributive reform policies such as land reform. This
29 For a Latin American view, see Veltmeyer (2005) for a similar, but not the same, typology involving
the first three types discussed in this section.
19
perspective follows the conventional framework which views land reform as a policy
that should provide secure access to and control over land resources to the landless
and nearlandless rural poor – through a state-led mechanism to expropriate land from
big landlords and to redistribute them to peasants. As partly explained in the country
cases in this study, such as the Ethiopian, Zimbabwean and the Philippine cases, a
state-led strategy is quite diverse, (historically) ranging from authoritarian to
‘democratic’ approaches (see, e.g. Tai, 1974; Riedinger, 1995). While this perspective
follows, in many cases, the economic basis of the market-led view, it also strongly
places the question of land reform in the context of social justice, explicitly calling for
the reform of inefficient, unjust and exploitative pre-existing agrarian structure.
Founded on the belief that market by itself will not redistribute, but rather may even
further concentration of wealth and power in society, this view calls for the central
state to muster strong ‘political will’ and mobilize significant funds to finance large
scale land reform. Tai (1974) represents this view, while the recent re-assertion made
by Barraclough (2001) can also be identified with this perspective.
The third common theme examined in this study is the role of peasant
movements and mobilizations for land. All the country case studies in this land policy
paper series analyze the role played by peasants’ actions, albeit the degree and extent
of analytic treatment varies from one country study to another, depending on the
prevailing conditions in these countries. For example, this theme receives greater
attention in Brazil and the Philippines, as compared to Armenia and Uzbekistan.
However, all the essays acknowledge the importance of peasants’ actions in land
policymaking and implementation, and have to address an existing distinct view in the
agrarian reform literature that assigns key role to peasants’ actions to any pro-poor
land policymaking and implementation. The perspective sees land reform in ways
very much similar to that of the state-led perspective, i.e. to provide secure access to
and control over land resources to landless and nearlandless poor in the context of
social justice and with the explicit goal of reforming the inefficient, unjust and
exploitative agrarian structure – but through peasant-led approach. Following the
state-led view that market by itself will not redistributive wealth and power, this
approach however is founded on the belief that the state by itself cannot also be relied
upon to carry out reform because usually it is captive to the dominant classes and
groups in society that are also opposed to redistributive reforms like land reform. The
peasant-led approach is exemplified by the ideological and political discourse by the
Movimento dos Trabalhadores Rurais Sem Terra (MST, Landless Rural Workers’
Movement) in Brazil in particular, and La Via Campesina more generally,30 and
scholars closely sympathetic to this view, such as James Petras (1997, 1998) and
Henry Veltmeyer (1997, 2005).31
30 For an analysis of the issue of agrarian reform focusing on La Via Campesina, see Borras (2004).
31 For excellent background on Via Campesina’s history, politics and ideology, see Desmarais
(forthcoming) and Edelman (2003).
Refer also the de Janvry, Sadoulet and Wolford (2001) for their analysis of the Brazilian landless
movement.
20
Table 2: Key features of various contending perspectives in agrarian reform
___________________________________________________________________________________
Perspective Features
Market-led Main consideration is economic efficiency/productivity gains;
gives secondary/marginal role to central states; peasants/beneficiaries who
are supposed to be in the ‘driver’s seat’ of the reform are actually
subordinated to the dominant market actors; in reality, ‘market-led’ means
‘landlord/merchant/TNC-led’ in many agrarian settings today.
State-led Main consideration is usually related to securing/maintaining political
legitimacy, though developmental agendas are also important; ‘strong
political will’ necessary to carry out land reform agenda;
usually treats peasants/beneficiaries as necessary administrative
adjuncts; subordinates market actors, or selectively deals with market actors
depending on which actors are more influential within the state.
Peasant-led Main assumption is that ‘state is too captive to societal elite interests’, while
market forces are basically dominated by elite interests = thus, the only way
to achieve pro-poor agrarian reform is for peasants and their organizations
by themselves to take the initiative to implement agrarian reform.
State/Society-driven Main assumptions: it does not romanticize the ‘omnipotence’ of
peasants/beneficiaries and their organizations; it does not assign
commanding role to central state; it does not provide sole importance to
economic productivity-enhancement issues = although it recognizes the
relevance of each of these perspectives; analyzes state, peasant movements,
and market forces not as separate groups, but as actors inherently linked to
each other by their association to the politics and economics of land
resources. It has three key features: ‘peasants/beneficiaries-led’, ‘statesupported’,
and ‘economic productivity-enhancing’.
___________________________________________________________________________________
The fourth common theme addressed by all papers in this study is the
interaction between state and society. As mentioned earlier, while it is important to
analyze the separate, distinct roles of the ‘free’ market, state and peasant movements,
it is equally crucial to examine them as inherently interlinked actors – focusing on the
interaction between them. All the country case studies in this research project
examine this theme within the perspective of state/society-driven land policymaking
and implementation process that views an ‘interactive’ state-society relationship that
largely determines the character, content, pace and direction of land reform policy
(Fox, 1993, 2004). This view also advocates for secure access to and control over land
resources by the landless and nearlandless rural poor within a social justice
framework. It has three key features: ‘peasants/beneficiaries-led’, ‘state-supported’,
and ‘economic productivity-enhancing’. While it highlights the importance of political
mobilizations ‘from below,’ it also puts equal weight to the reformist initiatives by
state actors ‘from above.’ It is founded on the belief that let alone, markets will not
only not lead to pro-poor redistributive reforms, it is even likely to further inequality
and poverty. Nevertheless, it does not altogether dismiss the positive role of the
market, although the latter needs to be governed by the state (see Wade, 2004, 1990).
Herring (1983), Borras (2001) and Franco (2005) represent this view.
The treatment to these different themes and the subsequent competing
perspectives as to their role in agrarian reform and rural development has evolved
21
amidst changing contexts for, and contested meanings of,32 land reform (as
summarized in Table 1). Assessing the outcomes of the diverse types of land policies
initiated in the 1990s onwards in terms of redistributing land to landless and
nearlandless peasants and in reducing rural poverty via different approaches is as
difficult a task as assessing past land reforms. Again, the record of contemporary land
reforms is varied and uneven between and within countries, as will be shown and
explained in the various essays in this research project. A crossnational comparative
analysis of these processes and outcomes, and their implications to agrarian reform
policymaking in particular and to the study of agrarian change more generally will be
explored in the concluding essay of this land policy paper series.
References
Abate, Alula and Fassil Kiros (1983). ‘Agrarian Reform, Structural Changes and Rural Development’,
in A.K. Ghose, ed. Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries, pp. 141-184. Geneva:
International Labour Organization; New York : St. Martin’s Press.
Agarwal, Bina (1994). A Field of One’s Own: Gender and Land Rights in South Asia. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Aguilar, Filomeno Jr. (2005). Rural Land Struggles in Asia: Overview of Selected Contexts, in S.
Moyo and P. Yeros, eds., Reclaiming the Land: The Resurgence of Rural Movements in Africa, Asia
and Latin America, pp. 208-234. London: Zed.
Akram-Lodhi, Haroon (2005) ‘Vietnam’s Agriculture: Processes of Rich Peasant Accumulation and
Mechanisms of Social Differentiation’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 5(1): 73-116.
Akram-Lodhi, Haroon (2004). ‘Are Landlords Taking Back the Land: An Essay on the Agrarian
Transition of Vietnam’, European Journal of Development Research, 16(2): 757-789.
Aspinal, Edward (2004). ‘Indonesia: Transformation of Civil Society and Democratic Breakthrough,’
in M. Alagappa, ed. Civil Society and Political Change in Asia, pp. 61-96. Stanford: Stanford
University Press.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Paul Gertler, and Maitreesh Ghatak (2002) ‘Empowerment and Efficiency: Tenancy
Reform in West Bengal’, Journal of Political Economy, 110(2): 239–80.
Baranyi, Stephen, Carmen Diana Deere and Manuel Morales (2004) Scoping Study on Land Policy
Research in Latin America. Ottawa: The North-South Institute; International Development
Research Centre (IDRC).
Barraclough, Solon (2001) ‘The Role of the State and Other Actors in Land Reform’, in K. Ghimire
(ed.) Land Reform and Peasant Livelihoods: The Social Dynamics of Rural Poverty and Agrarian
Reform in Developing Countries, pp. 26–64. Geneva: URISD; London: ITDG.
Barraclough, Solon (ed.) (1973) Agrarian Structure in Latin America: A Resume of the CIDA Land
Tenure Studies of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Guatemala, Peru. Lexington,
Massachussetts: Lexington Books.
Barraclough, Solon and A. Domike (1966). ‘Agrarian Structure in Seven Latin American Countries,’
Land Economics, 42(4): 391-424.
Barros, Flavia, Sergio Sauer, and Stephan Schwartzman (eds) (2003) The Negative Impacts of World
Bank Market-Based Land Reform. Brazil: Comissao Pastoral da Terra, Movimento dos
Trabalhadores Rurais Sem Terra (MST), Foodfirst Information and Action Network (FIAN).
Baruah, Sanjib (1990) ‘The End of the Road in Land Reform? Limits to Redistribution in West
Bengal’, Development and Change, 21(1): 119–46.
Bernstein, Henry (2004) ‘Changing Before Our Very Eyes: Agrarian Questions and the Politics of
Land in Capitalism Today’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 4(1/2): 190–225.
Bernstein, Henry (2003) ‘Land Reform in Southern Africa in World-Historical Perspective’, Review of
African Political Economy, 96: 21–46
Bernstein, Henry (2002) ‘Land Reform: Taking a Long(er) View’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 2(4):
433–63.
32 See, for example, the discussion by Borras and Franco (2005) about the contested meanings of ‘land
reform’ in the context of highly productive, capital-intensive, agribusiness plantations.
22
Bernstein, Henry (1998) ‘Social Change in the South African Countryside? Land and Production,
Poverty and Power’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 25 (4): 1–32.
Berry, Sara (2002) ‘Debating the Land Question in Africa’, Comparative Study in Society and History,
44(4): 638–68.
Berry, Albert and William Cline (1979) Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries.
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Binswanger, Hans and Klaus Deininger (1997) ‘Explaining Agricultural and Agrarian Policies in
Developing Countries’. A paper presented at the FAO Technical Consultation of Decentralization
and Rural Development, Rome, 16–18 Dec. 1997.
Binswanger, Hans and Klaus Deininger (1996) ‘South African Land Policy: The Legacy of History and
Current Options’, in J. v. Zyl, J. Kirsten and H.P. Binswanger (eds) Agricultural Land Reform in
South Africa: Policies, Markets and Mechanisms, pp. 64–104. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bobrow-Strain, Aaron (2004) ‘(Dis)Accords: The Politics of Market-Assisted Land Reforms in
Chiapas, Mexico’, World Development, 32(6): 887-903.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (forthcoming, 2006). ‘Redistributive Land Reform in Public (Forest) Lands?
Rethinking Theory and Practice with Evidence from the Philippines’, Progress in Development
Studies 6(2).
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2006) ‘The Philippine Land Reform in Comparative Perspective: Conceptual and
Methodological Implications’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 6(1): 69-101.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2005) ‘Can Redistributive Reform be Achieved via Market-Based Land Transfer
Schemes? Lessons and Evidence from the Philippines’, Journal of Development Studies, 41(1): 90–
134.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2004) ‘La Via Campesina: An Evolving Transnational Social Movement’, TNI
Briefing Series No. 2004/6. Amsterdam: Transnational Institute (for PDF version, see www.tni.org)
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2003a) ‘Questioning Market-Led Agrarian Reform: Experiences from Brazil,
Colombia and South Africa’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 3(3): 367–94.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2003b) ‘Questioning the Pro-Market Critique of State-led Agrarian Reform’,
European Journal of Development Research, 15(2): 105–28.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2003c) ‘Inclusion-Exclusion in Public Policies and Policy Analyses: The Case of
Philippine Land Reform, 1972–2002’, Journal of International Development, 15(8): 1049–1065.
Borras, Saturnino Jr (2001) ‘State-Society Relations in Land Reform Implementation in the
Philippines’, Development and Change, 32(3): 545–75.
Borras, Saturnino Jr. and Jennifer C. Franco (2005). ‘Struggles for Land and Livelihood in
Agribusiness Plantations in the Philippines’. Critical Asian Studies, 37(3) September.
Boyce, James (1993) The Political Economy of Growth and Impoverishment in the Marcos Era.
Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.
Branford, Sue and Jan Rocha (2002) Cutting the Wire: The Story of Landless Movement in Brazil.
London: Latin American Bureau.
Bratton, Michael (1990) ‘Ten Years After Land Redistribution in Zimbabwe, 1980–1990’, in R.
Prosterman, M. Temple, and T. Hanstad (eds) Agrarian Reform and Grassroots Development: Ten
Case Studies, pp. 265–91. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Bryant, Coralie (1996) ‘Strategic Change Through Sensible Projects’, World Development, 24(9):
1539–1550.
Bryceson, Deborah, Cristóbal Kay and Jos Mooij (eds) (2000) Disappearing Peasantries? Rural
Labour in Africa, Asia and Latin America. London: Intermediate Technology Publications.
Buainain, Márcio Antonio, José Maria da Silveira, Hildo Meireles Souza, and Marcelo Magalhães
(1999) ‘Community-Based Land Reform Implementation in Brazil: A New Way of Reaching Out
the Marginalized?’ A paper presented at the GDN Conference in Bonn, Germany, December 1999.
www.gdnet.org/ bonn99/confpapers.f1ml
Bush, Ray, ed. (2002). Counter-Revolution in Egypt’s Countryside: Land and Farmers in the Era of
Economic Reform. London: Zed.
Byres, Terence (2004a) ‘Introduction: Contextualizing and Interrogating the GKI Case for
Redistributive Land Reform’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 4(1/2): 1–16.
Byres, Terence (2004b) ‘Neo-Classical Neo-Populism 25 Years On: Déjà vu and Deja Passe: Towards
a Critique’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 4(1/2):17–44
Byres, Terence (1974) ‘Land Reform, Industrialization and the Marketed Surplus in India: An Essay on
the Power of Rural Bias’, in D. Lehmann (ed.) Peasants, Landlords and Governments: Agrarian
Reform in the Third World, pp. 221–61. New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers.
23
Carter, Michael (2000) ‘Old Questions and New Realities: Land in Post-Liberal Economies’, in A.
Zoomers and G. v.d. Haar (eds) Current Land Policy in Latin America: Regulating Land Tenure
Under Neo-Liberalism, pp. 29–44. Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute (KIT).
Carter, Michael and Ramón Salgado (2001) ‘Land Market Liberalization and the Agrarian Question in
Latin America’, in A. de Janvry, G. Gordillo, J.P.Platteau and E. Sadoulet (eds) Access to Land,
Rural Poverty, and Public Action, pp. 246–78. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Carter, Michael and Dina Mesbah (1993) ‘Can Land Market Reform Mitigate the Exclusionary Aspects
of Rapid Agro-Export Growth?’ World Development, 21(7): 1085–1100.
Castillo, Leonardo and David Lehmann (1983). ‘Agrarian Reform and Structural Change in Chile,
1965-79,’ in A.K. Ghose, ed. Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries, pp. 240-
272. Geneva: International Labour Organization; New York : St. Martin’s Press.
Christodoulou, D. (1990). The Unpromised Land: Agrarian reform and Conflict Worldwide. London:
Zed.
Collins, Joseph with Frances Moore Lappé and N. Allen (1982) What Difference Could a Revolution
Make? Food and Farming in the New Nicaragua. San Francisco, CA: Institute for Food and
Development Policy.
Cousins, Ben (1997) ‘How Do Rights Become Real? Formal and Institutions in South Africa’s Land
Reform’, IDS Bulletin, 28(4): 59–67.
CPRC (2005). The Chronic Poverty Report 2005-05. Manchester: Chronic Poverty Research Centre,
University of Manchester.
Deere, Carmen Diana (2000) ‘Towards a Reconstruction of Cuba’s Agrarian Transformation:
Peasantization, De-peasantization and Re-peasantization’, in D. Bryceson, C. Kay, and J. Mooij
(eds) Disappearing Peasantries? – Rural Labour in Africa, Asia and Latin America, pp. 139–58.
London: ITDG.
Deere, Carmen Diana (1985) ‘Rural Women and State Policy: The Latin American Agrarian Reform
Experience’, World Development, 13(9), 1037–1053.
Deere, Carmen Diana and Magdalena León (2001) ‘Who Owns the Land: Gender and Land-Titling
Programmes in Latin America’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 1(3): 440–67.
de Janvry, Alain (1981) The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America. Baltimore: The Johns
Hopkins University Press.
de Janvry, Alain, Gustavo Gordillo, Jean-Philippe Platteau and Elisabeth Sadoulet (eds) (2001) Access
to Land, Rural Poverty,and Public Action. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
de Janvry, Alain, Elisabeth Sadoulet, and Wendy Wolford (2001) ‘The Changing Role of the State in
Latin American Land Reform’, in de Janvry, G. Gordillo, J.P. Platteau and E. Sadoulet (eds) Access
to Land, Rural Poverty, and Public Action, pp. 279–303. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
de Janvry, Alain and Elisabeth Sadouleth (1989) ‘A Study in Resistance to Institutional Change: The
Lost Game of Latin American Land Reform’, World Development, 17(9):1397–1407.
de Soto, Hernando (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.
Deininger, Klaus (1999) ‘Making Negotiated Land Reform Work: Initial Experience from Colombia,
Brazil and South Africa’, World Development, 27(4): 651–672.
Deininger, Klaus (1995). ‘Collective Agricultural Production: A Solution for Transition Economies?’,
World Development, 23(8): 1317-34.
Deininger, Klaus (2002). ‘Agrarian Reforms in Eastern European Countries: Lessons from
International Experience,’ Journal of International Development, 14(7): 987-1003.
Deininger, Klaus and Hans Binswanger (1999) ‘The Evolution of the World Bank’s Land Policy:
Principles, Experience and Future Challenges’, The World Bank Research Observer, 14(2): 247–
276.
Desmarais, Annette (forthcoming). ‘The Power of Peasants: Reflections on the Meanings of the Via
Campesina,’ Journal of Rural Studies.
Diskin, Martin (1989) ‘El Salvador: Reform Prevents Change’, in W. Thiesenhusen (ed.) Searching for
Agrarian Reform in Latin America, pp. 429–50. Boston: Unwin Hyman.
Dorner, Peter (1992) Latin American Land Reforms in Theory and Practice. WI: University of
Wisconsin Press.
Dorner, Peter and Don Kanel (1971) The Economic Case for Land Reform, in Land Reform, Land
Settlements and Cooperatives, 1971(1): 1–16
Edelman, Marc (2003). ‘Transnational Peasant and Farmer Movements and Networks,’ in M. Kaldor,
H. Anheier and M. Glasius, eds. Global Civil Society, pp. 185-220. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
24
El-Ghonemy, Riad (2001) ‘The Political Economy of Market-Based Land Reform’, in K. Ghimire (ed.)
Land Reform and Peasant Livelihoods: The Social Dynamics of Rural Poverty and Agrarian
Reform in Developing Countries, pp. 105–133. Geneva: UNRISD; London: ITDG.
El-Ghonemy, Riad (1990) The Political Economy of Rural Poverty: The Case for Land Reform. New
York/London: Routledge.
Ellis, Frank (2000) Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Developing Countries. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Fagan, Richard, Carmen Diana Deere and Jose Luis Corragio (eds.) (1986). Transition and
Development: Problems of Third World Socialism. New York: Monthly Review Press.
FIAN-Via Campesina (2003) ‘Commentary on Land and Rural Development Policies of the World
Bank’. Heidelberg/Honduras:
FitzGerald, E.V.K. (1985) ‘Agrarian Reform as a Model of Accumulation: The Case of Nicaragua
since 1979’, Journal of Development Studies, 22(1): 208-220.
Foley, Michael (1997). ‘Land and Peace in Postwar El Salvador: Structural Adjustment, Land Reform
and Social Peace in the Salvadoran Countryside.’ Research for the Washington Office on Latin
America (WOLA) on the World Bank and agrarian policy in postwar El Salvador.
Fortin, Elizabeth (2005). ‘Reforming Land Rights: The World Bank and the Globalisation of
Agriculture,’ Social and Legal Studies, 14(2).
Fox, Jonathan (2004). ‘Empowerment and Institutional Change: Mapping “Virtuous Circles” of State-
Society Interaction, in R. Alsop, ed., Power, Rights and Poverty: Concepts and Connections, pp.
68-92. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fox, Jonathan (1993) The Politics of Food in Mexico: State Power and Social Mobilization. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press.
Fox, Jonathan (ed.) (1990) The Challenges of Rural Democratisation: Perspectives from Latin America
and the Philippines. London: Frank Cass.
Franco, Jennifer, 2005. ‘Making Property Rights Accessible: Movement Innovation in the Political
Legal Struggle to Claim Land Rights in the Philippines.’ IDS Working Paper Series, no. 244 (June,
2005) Institute of Development Studies (IDS), Brighton (for PDF version
www.ids.ac.uk/ids/bookshop/wp/wp244.pdf).
Franco, Jennifer (2001) Elections and Democratization in the Philippines. New York: Routledge;
Quezon City: Institute for Popular Democracy.
Franco, Jennifer and Saturnino Borras Jr., eds. (2005). On Just Grounds: Struggling for Agrarian
Justice and Citizenship Rights in the Rural Philippines. Quezon City: Institute for Popular
Democracy; Amsterdam: Transnational Institute.
Friedmann, Harriet (2005). ‘Feeding the Empire: The Pathologies of Globalized Agriculture,’ in
L. Panitch and C. Leys, eds. The Empire Reloaded. Toronto: Socialist Register.
Ghai, Dharam, Cristóbal Kay, and Peter Peek (1988). Labour and Development in Rural Cuba.
London: Macmillan.
Ghimire, Krishna (ed.) (2005). Civil Society and the Market Question: Dynamics of Rural Development
and Popular Mobilization. London: Palgrave; Geneva: UNRISD.
Ghimire, Krishna (ed.) (2001) Land Reform and Peasant Livelihoods: The Social Dynamics of Rural
Poverty and Agrarian Reform in Developing Countries. Geneva: UNRISD; London: ITDG.
Ghose, Ajit Kumar (ed.) (1983a) Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Countries. Geneva: International
Labour Organization; New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Ghose, Ajit Kumar (1983b). Agrarian Reform in West Bengal: Objectives, Achievements and
Limitations,’ in A.K. Ghose, ed. Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries, pp. 91-
140. Geneva: International Labour Organization; New York : St. Martin’s Press
Goodman, David and Michael Watts (1997). Globalising Food: Agrarian Questions and Global
Restructuring. London: Routledge.
Greenberg, Stephen (2004). ‘The Landless People’s Movement and the failure of Post-Apartheid Land
Reform’. Durban: KwaZulu-Natal, School of Development Studies.
Griffin, Keith (1976) Land Concentration and Rural Poverty. London: Macmillan Press.
Griffin, Keith (1974). The Political Economy of Agrarian Change: An Essay on the Green Revolution.
London: Macmillan Press.
Griffin, Keith, Azizur Rahman Khan and Amy Ickowitz (2002) ‘Poverty and Distribution of Land’,
Journal of Agrarian Change, 2(3): 279–330.
Griffin, Keith and Terry McKinley (1994). Implementing a Human Development Strategy. London:
Macmillan.
Grindle, Merilee (1986) State and Countryside: Development Policy and Agrarian Politics in Latin
America. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
25
Gwynne, Robert and Cristóbal Kay (2004) Latin America Transformed: Globalization and Modernity.
London: Arnold (second edition).
Handy, Jim (1994) Revolution in the Countryside: Rural Conflict and Agrarian Reform in Guatemala,
1944–1954. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.
Harriss, John (1993) ‘What is Happening in Rural West Bengal? Agrarian Reform, Growth and
Distribution’, Economic and Political Weekly, XXVIII, pp. 1237-1247.
Harriss, John, ed. (1982) Rural Development: Theories of Peasant Economy and Agrarian Change.
London: Routledge.
Harvey, Neil (1998) The Chiapas Rebellion: The Struggle for Land and Democracy. Durnham: Duke
University Press.
Herring, Ronald (2003) ‘Beyond the Political Impossibility Theorem of Agrarian Reform’, in P.
Houtzager and M. Moore (eds) Changing Paths: International Development and the New Politics of
Inclusion, pp. 58-87. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press.
Herring, Ronald (2002). ‘State Property Rights in Nature (With Special Reference to India)’, in F.
Richards, ed. Land, Property, and the Environment, pp. 263-297. Oakland: Institute for
Contemporary Studies.
Herring, Ronald (1983) Land to the Tiller: The Political Economy of Agrarian Reform in South Asia.
New Haven: Yale University Press.
Hernáiz, I., D. Pacheco, R. Guerrero and H. Miranda (2000), Análisis Crítico del Proceso de Catastro
Rural Legal y Saneamiento Integrado al Catastro Legal en el Departamento de Chuquisaca
(KADASTER e INRA), La Paz and Sucre: Fundación TIERRA.
Hobsbawm, Eric (1974) ‘Peasant Land Occupations’, Past and Present, (62): 120–52.
Houtzager, Peter (2000) ‘Social Movements amidst Democratic Transitions: Lessons from the
Brazilian Countryside’, Journal of Development Studies, 36(5): 59–88.
Huizer, Gerrit (2001) ‘Peasant Mobilization for Land Reform: Historical Case Studies and Theoretical
Considerations’, in K. Ghimire (ed.) Land Reform and Peasant Livelihoods: The Social Dynamics
of Rural Poverty and Agrarian Reform in Developing Countries, pp. 164–198. London: ITDG.
Jacoby, Erich (with Charlotte Jacoby) (1971) Man and Land: The Fundamental Issue in Development.
London: André Deutsch.
Jansen, Kees and Esther Roquas (1998). ‘Modernizing Insecurity: the Land Titling Project in
Honduras,’ Development and Change, 29(1): 81-106.
Jones, P.M. (1991) ‘The “Agrarian Law”: Schemes for Land Redistribution During the French
Revolution’, Past and Present, (133): 96–133.
Johnston, Deborah (forthcoming). ‘On Shaky Foundations? The Implications for Land Reform of
Unreconstructed Thinking about Households,’ Development and Change.
Kabeer, Naila (1995). Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London:
Verso.
Karshenas, Massoud (2004) ‘Urban Bias, Intersectoral Resource Flows and the Macroeconomic
Implications of Agrarian Relations: The Historical Experience of Japan and Taiwan’, Journal of
Agrarian Change, 4(1/2): 170–189.
Kay, Cristóbal (2004) ‘Rural Livelihoods and Peasant Futures’, in R. Gwynne and C. Kay (eds) Latin
America Transformed: Globalization and Modernity, pp. 232-250. London: Arnold (2nd edition).
Kay, Cristóbal (2002) ‘Why East Asia overtook Latin America: Agrarian Reform, Industrialization and
Development’, Third World Quarterly, 23(6): 1073-1102.
Kay, Cristóbal (2001) ‘Reflections on Rural Violence in Latin America’, Third World Quarterly, 22(5):
741–75.
Kay, Cristóbal (1998) ‘Latin America’s Agrarian Reform: Lights and Shadows’, Land Reform, Land
Settlements and Cooperatives, 1998(2): 9–31.
Kay, Cristóbal (1983) ‘The Agrarian Reform in Peru: An Assessment’, in A.K. Ghose (ed.) Agrarian
Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries, pp. 185–239. London/New York: Croom Helm
Ltd/St. Martin’s Press.
Kay, Cristóbal and Patricio Silva (eds) (1992) Development and Social Change in the Chilean
Countryside: From the Pre-Land Reform Period to the Democratic Consolidation. Amsterdam:
CEDLA.
Kerkvliet, Benedict (2005). The Power of Everyday Politics: How Vietnamese Peasants Transformed
National Policy. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kerkvliet, Benedict (1993) ‘Claiming the Land: Take-overs by Villagers in the Philippines with
Comparisons to Indonesia, Peru, Portugal, and Russia’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 20(3):459–93.
Kerkvliet, Benedict, ed. (1994). Dilemmas of Development: Vietnam Update 1994. Political and
Social Change Monograph 22, Canberra: Australian National University.
26
King, Russell (1977) Land Reform: A World Survey. London: B. Bell and Sons Ltd.
Korovkin, Tanya (2000). ‘Weak Weapons, Strong Weapons: Hidden Resistance and Political protest in
Rural Ecuador’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 27(3): 1-29.
Lahiff, Edward (2003) ‘Land Reform and Sustainable Livelihood in South Africa’s Eastern Cape
Province’. IDS Research Paper No. 9, Brighton: Institute of Development Studies, March 2003.
Lahiff, Edward and Ian Scoones (2000) ‘Sustainable Livelihoods in Southern Africa: Institutions,
Governance and Policy Processes’, Sustainable Livelihood Southern Africa (SLSA) Research Paper
2, Brighton, Sussex: Institute of Development Studies.
Landsberger, Henry (ed.) (1974) Rural Protest: Peasant Movements and Social Change. London:
Macmillan.
Lappé, Frances Moore, Joseph Collins and Peter Rosset (1998). World Hunger: Twelve Myths.
Berkeley: Food First Books (2nd edition).
Lara, Francisco Jr and Horacio Morales Jr (1990) ‘The Peasant Movement and the Challenge of
Democratisation in the Philippines’, in J. Fox (ed.) The Challenge of Rural Democratisation:
Perspectives from Latin America and the Philippines, Journal of Development Studies, (special
issue) 26(4): 143–62.
Lebert, Tom (2001) ‘Tinkering at the Edges: Land Reform in South Africa – 1994 to 2001’. A Paper
prepared for the International Conference on Access to Land: Innovative Agrarian Reforms for
Sustainability and Poverty Reduction,’ 19–23 March 2001, Bonn, Germany.
Lehmann, David (ed.) (1974) Peasants, Landlords and Governments: Agrarian Reform in the Third
World. New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers.
Levin, Richard and Daniel Weiner (eds) (1997) Struggles for Land in Mpumalanga, South Africa.
NJ/Eritrea: Africa World Press.
Lieten, G.K. (1996) ‘Land Reforms at Centre Stage: The Evidence on West Bengal’, Development and
Change, 26(1): 111–30.
Lipton, Michael (1974) ‘Towards a Theory on Land Reform’, in D. Lehmann (ed) Peasants, Landlords
and Governments: Agrarian Reform in the Third World, pp. 269–315. New York: Holmes and
Meier Publishers.
Lucas, Anton and Carol Warren (2003). ‘The State, The People and Their Mediators: The Struggle
over Agrarian Law Reform in Post New Order Indonesia’, Indonesia, no. 76 (October 2003).
Magdoff, Fred, Frederick Buttel, and John Bellamy Foster, eds. (1998). ‘Hungry for Profit:
Agriculture, Food, and Ecology’, Monthly Review, 50(3).
Matondi, Prosper and Sam Moyo (2003) ‘Experiences with Market Based Land Reform in Zimbabwe’,
in F. Barros et al (eds) The Negative Impacts of World Bank Market Based Land Reform, pp. 323–
402. Brazil: CPT and MST.
McAuslan, Patrick (2000) ‘Only the Name of the Country Changes: The Diaspora of “European” Land
Law in Commonwealth Africa, in C. Toulmin and J. Quan (eds) Evolving Land Rights, Policy and
Tenure in Africa. London: DFID/IIED/ NRI.
McMichael, Philip, ed. (1995). Food and Agrarian Order in the World Economy. CT: Praeger.
Meszaros, George (2000) ‘No Ordinary Revolution: Brazil’s Landless Workers’ Movement’, Race and
Class, 42(2): 1-18.
Monsalve, Sofia (2004). ‘EU land policy guidelines and the human right approach to land’, paper
presented at a seminar on the European Union Land Policies for Developing Countries, Brussels,
17 April 2004, sponsored by Foodfirst Information and Action Network (FIAN).
Moore, Barrington Jr (1967) Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the
Modern World. Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Moyo, Sam (2000) ‘The Political Economy of Land Acquisition and Redistribution in Zimbabwe,
1990–1999’, Journal of Southern African Studies, 26(1): 5–28.
Moyo, Sam and Paris Yeros (2005). ‘The Resurgence of Rural Movements Under Neoliberalism,’ in S.
Moyo and P. Yeros, eds., Reclaiming the Land: The Resurgence of Rural Movements in Africa, Asia
and Latin America, pp. 8-66. London: Zed.
Navarro, Zander (1998) ‘The “Cédula da Terra” Guiding Project – Comments on the Social and
Political-Institutional Conditions of its Recent Development’. www.dataetrra.org.br.
Nuijten, Monique (2003). ‘Family Property and the Limits of Intervention: The Article 27 Reforms and
the PROCEDE Programme in Mexico’, Development and Change, 34(3): 475-497.
O’Laughlin, Bridget (1996) ‘Through a Divided Glass: Dualism, Class and the Agrarian Questions in
Mozambique’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 23(4): 1–39.
O’Laughlin, Bridget (1995) ‘Past and Present Options: Land Reform in Mozambique’, Review of
African Political Economy, (63): 99–106.
27
Paasch, Armin (2003) ‘The Failure of Market-Assisted Land Reforms and Some Necessary
Consequences: Comments on the World Bank’s Policy Research Report’.
http://www.worldbank.org/landpolicy/.
Paige, Jeffrey (1975) Agrarian Revolution: Social Movements and Export Agriculture in the
Underdeveloped World. New York: Free Press.
Palmer, Robin (2000a) ‘Land Policy in Africa: Lessons from Recent Policy and Implementation
Processes’, in C. Toulmin and J. Quan (eds) Evolving Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa, pp.
267-88. London: DFID/IIED/NRI.
Palmer, Robin (2000b) ‘Mugabe’s “Land Grab” in Regional Perspective’, in T.A.S. Bowyer-Bower
and C. Stoneman (eds) Land Reform in Zimbabwe: Constraints and Prospects, pp. 15-23.
Aldershot: Ashgate.
Pearce, Jenny (1998). ‘From Civil war to Civil Society: Has the End of the Cold War Brought Peace in
Central America?,’ International Affairs, 74(3): 587-615.
Petras, James (1997) ‘Latin America: The Resurgence of the Left’, New Left Review, (223): 17–47.
Petras, James (1998) ‘The Political and Social Basis of Regional Variation in Land Occupations in
Brazil’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 25(4): 124–33.
Platteau, Jean-Philippe (1996) ‘The Evolutionary Theory of Land Rights as Applied to Sub-Saharan
Africa: A Critical Assessment’, Development and Change, 27(1): 29–86.
Pons-Vignon, Nicolas and Henri-Bernard Solignac Lecomte (2004) Land, Violent Conflict and
Development. OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 233.
Prosterman, Roy, Mary Temple, and Timothy Hanstad (eds) (1990) Agrarian Reform and Grassroots
Development: Ten Cases. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Putzel, James (2000) ‘Land Reforms in Asia: Lessons from the Past for the 21st Century’, LSE Working
Paper Series, No. 00-04. London: London School of Economics.
Putzel, James (1992) A Captive Land: The Politics of Agrarian Reform in the Philippines. London:
Catholic Institute for International Relations; New York: Monthly Review Press; Quezon City:
Ateneo de Manila University Press.
Quan, Julian (2000) ‘Land Tenure, Economic Growth and Poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa’, in C.
Toulmin and J. Quan (eds) Evolving Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa, pp. 31-49. London:
DFID/IIED/NRI.
Raj, K.N. and Michael Tharakan (1983). ‘Agrarian Reform in Kerala and its Impact on the Rural
Economy’, in A. K. Ghose, ed. Agrarian Reform in Contemporary Developing Countries, pp. 31-
90. Geneva: International Labour Organization; New York : St. Martin’s Press.
Razavi, Shahra (2003) ‘Introduction: Agrarian Change, Gender and Land Rights’, Journal of Agrarian
Change, (special issue) 3(1/2): 2–32.
Redclift, Michael (1978) Agrarian Reform and Peasant Organization on the Ecuadorian Coast.
London: University of London/The Athlone Press.
Reyes, Ricardo (1999) ‘Market-Assisted Land Reform: An Indecent Proposal’. http://www.philsol.nl
Ribot, Jesse and Anne Larson (2005). Democratic Decentralisation through a Natural Resource Lens.
New York: Routledge.
Riedinger, Jeffrey (1995) Agrarian Reform in the Philippines: Democratic Transitions and
Redistributive Reform. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Riedinger, Jeffrey, Wan-Ying Yang and Karen Brook (2000) ‘Market-Based Land Reform: An
Imperfect Solution’, in H. Morales Jr and J. Putzel (eds) (2001) Power in the Village: Agrarian
Reform, Rural Politics, Institutional Change and Globalization, pp. 363–78. Quezon City:
University of the Philippines Press.
Ross, Eric (2003). ‘Modernisation, Clearance and the Continuum of Violence in Colombia’. ISS
Working Paper Series no. 383, The Hague: Institute of Social Studies.
Ross, Eric (1998) The Malthus Factor: Poverty, Politics and Population in Capitalist Development.
London: Zed.
Rosset, Peter (2001) ‘Tides Shift on Agrarian Reform: New Movements Show the Way’,
Backgrounder, 7(1): 1–8. Berkeley: Foodfirst Institute.
Sadoulet, Elisabeth, Rinku Murgai, and Alain de Janvry (2001) ‘Access to Land via Land Rental
Markets’, in A. de Janvry, G. Gordillo, J.P.Platteau and E. Sadoulet (eds) Access to Land, Rural
Poverty, and Public Action, pp. 196–229. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Saith, Ashwani (1985) ‘Primitive Accumulation, Agrarian Reform and Socialist Transitions: An
Argument’, Journal of Development Studies, 22(1): 1-48.
Sauer, Sergio (2003) ‘A Ticket to Land: The World Bank’s Market-Based Land Reform in Brazil’, F.
Barros et al (eds), The Negative Impacts of World Bank Market-Based Land Reform, pp. 45–102.
28
Brazil: Comissao Pastoral da Terra, Movimento dos Trabalhadores Rurais Sem Terra (MST),
Foodfirst Information and Action Network (FIAN).
Scott, James (1998) Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have
Failed. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Shillinglaw, Geoffrey (1974) ‘Land Reform and Peasant Mobilization in Southern China, 1947–1950’,
in D. Lehmann (ed.) Peasants, Landlords and Governments: Agrarian Reform in the Third World,
pp. 118–55. New York: Holmes and Meier Publishers
Sobhan, Rehman (1993) Agrarian Reform and Social Transformation. London: Zed.
Spoor, Max (ed.) (2003) Transition, Institutions, and the Rural Sector. New York: Lexington.
Spoor, Max (2002). ‘Policy Regimes and Performance of the Agricultural Sector in Latin America and
the Caribbean During the Last Three Decades’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 2(3): 381-400.
Spoor, Max (ed.) (1997) The ‘Market Panacea’: Agrarian Transformation in Developing Countries
and Former Socialist Economies. London: Intermediate Technology Publications.
Spoor, Max and Oane Visser (2004). ‘Restructuring Postponed: Large Russian Farm Enterprises
“Coping with the Market”’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 31(3/4): 515-551.
Stavenhagen, Rodolfo (ed.) (1971) Agrarian Problems and Peasant Movements in Latin America. New
York: Anchor Books.
Tai, Hung-Chao (1974) Land Reform and Politics: A Comparative Analysis. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Tannenbaum, Frank (1929) The Mexican Agrarian Revolution. New York: Archon Books (published
again in 1968).
Thiesenhusen, William (1995) Broken Promises: Agrarian Reform and the Latin American Campesino.
Boulder: Westview.
Thiesenhusen, William (ed.) (1989) Searching for Agrarian Reform in Latin America. Boston: Unwin
Hyman.
Toulmin, Camilla and Julian Quan (eds) (2000) Evolving Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa.
London: DFID/IIED/NRI.
Tsing, Anna (2002). ‘Land as Law: Negotiating the Meaning of Property in Indonesia’, in F. Richards,
ed. Land, Property, and the Environment, pp. 94-137. Oakland: Institute for Contemporary Studies.
Tuma, Elias (1965) Twenty-Six Centuries of Agrarian Reform: A Comparative Analysis. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Urioste, Miguel (2001). ‘Bolivia: Reform and Resistance in the Countryside (1982-2000).’ London:
University of London, Institute of Latin American Studies Occasional Papers, no. 23.
van den Hombergh, Heleen (2004). No Stone Unturned: Building Blocks of Environmentalist
Campaigning versus Transnational Industrial Forestry in Costa Rica. Amsterdam: Dutch
University Press.
Veltmeyer, Henry (2005). ‘The Dynamics of Land Occupations in Latin America,’ in S. Moyo and P.
Yeros, eds., Reclaiming the Land: The Resurgence of Rural Movements in Africa, Asia and Latin
America, pp. 285-316. London: Zed.
Veltmeyer, Henry (1997) ‘New Social Movements in Latin America: The Dynamics of Class and
Identity’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 25(1): 139–69.
Wade, Robert (2004). ‘Is Globalization Reducing Poverty and Inequality’, World Development,
32(4): 567-89.
Wade, Robert (1990). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in
East Asian Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Walinsky, Louis (ed.) (1977) Agrarian Reform as Unfinished Business: The Selected Papers of Wolf
Ladejinsky. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Warriner, Doreen (1969) Land Reform in Principle and Practice. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Wiradi, Gunawan (2005). ‘Agrarian Reform Movement in Indonesia: Past and Present’. Paper
presented at the workshop on ‘Food Sovereignty and Agrarian Reform Movement in Indonesia’,
organized by the CCFD, Paris, 03 February 2005.
Wolf, Eric (1969) Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century. New York/London: Harper and Row
Wolford, Wendy (2003) ‘Producing Community: The MST and Land Reform Settlements in Brazil’,
Journal of Agrarian Change, 3(4): 500–20.
Worby, Eric (2001) ‘A Redivided Land? New Agrarian Conflicts and Questions in Zimbabwe’,
Journal of Agrarian Change, 1(4): 475–509.
World Bank (2005). World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development. Washington DC:
World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank (2003) Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. Washington D.C.: World Bank;
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
29
Wright, Angus and Wendy Wolford (2003) To Inherit the Earth: The Landless Movement and the
Struggle for a New Brazil. Oakland, CA: Food First Books.
Wuyts, Marc (1994). ‘Accumulation, Industrialisation and the Peasantry: A Reinterpretation of the
Tanzanian Experience’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 21(2): 159-193.
Yashar, Deborah (2005). Contesting Citizenship in Latin America; The Rise of Indigenous Movements
and the Postliberal Challenge, Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Yashar, Deborah (1999). ‘Democracy, Indigenous Movements, and the Postliberal Challenge in
Latin America’, World Politics, 52(1): 76-104.
Zoomers, Annelies and Gemma van der Haar (eds) (2000) Current Land Policy in Latin America:
Regulating Land Tenure Under Neo-Liberalism. Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute (KIT).
30
The ISS/UNDP Land, Poverty and Public Action Policy Papers
No. 1 Agrarian Reform and Rural Development: Historical Overview and Current
Issues
Saturnino M. Borras Jr., Cristóbal Kay and A. Haroon Akram Lodhi
No. 2 Agrarian Reform and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from Brazil
Carmen Diana Deere and Leonilde Servolo de Medeiros
No. 3 Bolivia's Unfinished Agrarian Reform: Rural Poverty and Development
Policies
Cristóbal Kay and Miguel Urioste
No. 4 Land Markets and Rural Livelihoods in Vietnam
A. Haroon Akram Lodhi
No. 5 Land, Poverty, and State-Society Interaction in the Philippines
Saturnino M. Borras Jr., Danilo Carranza, and Ricardo Reyes
No. 6 Land Reform, Rural Poverty, and Inequality in Armenia:
A Pro-Poor Approach to Land Policies
Max Spoor
No. 7 Land System, Agriculture and Poverty in Uzbekistan
Azizur Rahman Khan
No. 8 Land Reform in Namibia: Issues of Equity and Poverty
Jan Kees van Donge with George Eiseb and Alfons Mosimane
No. 9 Untying the Gordian Knot: The Question of Land Reform in Ethiopia
Gebru Mersha and Mwangi wa Githinji
No. 10 Mubarak’s Legacy for Egypt’s Rural Poor: Returning Land to the Landlords
Ray Bush
No. 11 Land Policy, Poverty Reduction and Public Action in Zimbabwe
Sam Moyo
No. 12 Land, Poverty and Public Action: Implications for the Agrarian Question in
an Era of Globalization
A. Haroon Akram Lodhi, Saturnino M. Borras Jr., and Cristóbal Kay

Tidak ada komentar: